Wednesday, June 14, 2017

The Rise and Fall of American Growth

The subtitle is The U.S. Standard of Living Since the Civil War and the author is Robert J. Gordon (2016).

The overarching premise is that American growth apexes in the period from 1870-1970, and has been in steady decline ever since (with a short blip in the period from 1994-2004).  Part of the explanation is that many of the most important innovations and inventions that improved quality of life happened in that period, and were the sorts of the things that could only happen once – such as the internal combustion engine that brought cars and railroads to replace horses, electricity and the light bulb, clean water and municipal sewer systems, and refrigeration that enabled far less contamination of food.  All of these contributed to efficiencies in productivity and improvements in mortality rates and the overall standard of living, drawing people off the farms and into urban centers.

By contrast, in looking at the period since 1970 (defined as the “computer age”), beyond seeing only incremental improvements to the earlier ideas, the presence of greater income inequality has also compounded problems when looking at more recent growth and productivity statistics.  With respect to technological innovation, the author feels that good, steady, middle-level jobs have been lost to robots and algorithms, but also to the accompanying globalization and outsourcing, leaving behind mostly lower wage positions.  And in drawing the nexus to a more prevalent wage inequality since 1970, the author suggests looking at it top down and bottoms up.  In other words, at the higher end, Gordon believes that incomes have increased meaningfully because of changing economics for superstars, changing incentives for executive compensation, and capital gains on real estate and stocks.  Looking at the other end, he sees weakened labor unions, increased automation, declining purchasing power of the minimum wage, greater imports hollowing out the manufacturing sector, and greater immigration as contributors to lower wage rates for everyone outside the top percentiles.  What’s interesting, though, is in looking at the golden age of growth from 1945-1975, the author attributes the rise of unionization and the decline of global trade and immigration as explanations to the greater wage equality.  Ponder that last bit.

Anyway, as a last point, the author delves into an area that I find interesting, which is the question of whether WW2 brought economic prosperity to this country after the Great Depression.  He does generally support the premise, but with seemingly more nuance than the typical economist who says that any spending will do as fiscal stimulus, regardless of the purpose in mind.  To put a finer point on it, it was not simply the act of government spending in the war effort, it was in the technological innovation that came out of firms that were forced to boost output in spite of limited capital and labor.  Those innovations and changes did not regress simply because the war ended, and therefore, when paired with pent-up demand after wartime rationing, allowed productivity to remain high.  In other words, without that level of technological innovation, fiscal stimulus, even on the scale of war, does not automatically produce the ends that are often ascribed to it.

Broken Money

The subtitle is Why Our Financial System is Failing Us and How We Can Make it Better , and the author is Lyn Alden (2023). I feel like I hav...